Mixed-Income versus Low-Income Housing
Session: Mixed-Income versus Low-Income Housing
April 2, 10:15 AM
Kirk
McClure
University of Kansas
Abstract
Much has been learned about the development and operation of low-income housing.
The consensus is that concentrating low-income households into designated assisted
housing projects creates social, political and economic problems. Adopting an
approach striving for mixed-income housing can alleviate these problems.
Methods to foster mixed-income housing range across housing typessingle-family
and multi-family as well as owner-occupied and renter-occupied. The methods
vary from regulatory mechanisms to financial incentives.
Creating successful mixed-income housing requires that planners understand
the market conditions, the design constraints, the management skills and the
marketing strategies necessary.
Introduction
The concept of mixed-income housingdevelopments that are occupied by
households of varied income levelsis an idea gaining popular support at
many levels. This support is for good reason. Assisted developments serving
only the poor are often associated with social, political and economic problems.
Some and possibly all of these problems can be alleviated through the redesign
of housing assistance where the assisted households comprise only a small portion
of the total households in the development.
Planners need to take a leadership position in implementing this approach. Elected
decision makers cannot be expected to be fully informed of the housing options
available to them when setting the housing strategies for the community. Planners
should adopt the role of educator when guiding decision makers on housing strategy
selection. Mixed-income housing is a policy option that all planners should
be exploring for use in their communities.
Schwartz and Tajbakhsh (1997), in their review of the research on mixed-income,
warn that much of the advocacy for the concept of mixed-income housing is based
largely on faith and on dissatisfaction with the previous thrust of low-income
housing policy. As planners, we should not simply rush toward mixed-income
housing because we are rushing away from the problems created by low-income
housing. However, there is much merit in the concept of mixed-income housing.
Planners time and effort in this area will be rewarded. Fortunately, the
concept is not new, and as a result, a great deal of research is available which
will guide the planner in understanding when and where mixed-income housing
can be effectively developed.
Defining Mixed-Income Housing
Many definitions of mixed-income housing exist. No one definition is necessarily
superior to all others. Each has an appropriate application depending upon the
setting. However, at its core, the concept of mixed-income housing implies that
the mixed-income housing development have residents with a range of income levels.
This range would normally include some households who are of low-income and
some households who are not.
Given the many and varied definitions of low-income that exist, defining mixed-income
housing is as difficult as defining low-income, especially to those uninitiated
with the variety of program constraints that confront a housing planner. For
example, low-income is usually defined in relation to the metropolitan area
median family income (AMFI) level. Low-income is typically defined by HUD as
an income that places the household at or below 80 percent of the metropolitan
areas median family income. This is often adjusted for household size
with lower levels for smaller households and higher levels for larger families.
However, this 80 percent level does not apply to all programs. The Low-Income
Housing Tax Credit (LIHTC) program defines low-income as being at or below 50
percent of the area median family income and refers to those between 50 and
60 percent of the area median as being of moderate-income. HUD often refers
to those below the 50 percent mark as being of very low-income and goes still
further calling those below 30 percent as being of extremely low-income. This
last group with income at or below 30 percent of the areas median family
income approximates the group that is below the poverty level.
Thus, the definition of low-income is subject to some variation. If the concept
of mixed-income involves mixing low-income households with households of higher
income, then is important to understand just what is meant by low-income. One
approach to mixed-income may mean mixing households below poverty (at or below
30 percent of AMFI) with households who would be thought of as the working poor
(between 50 percent and 80 percent of the AMFI). However, under this definition,
all of the residents would meet HUDs broadest definition of low-income.
An alternative approach may involve mixing households with modest income such
as teachers and other city employees (50 to 80 percent of AMFI) with households
whose income places them above the AMFI. This approach may mix low-income with
middle- or upper-income households, but it may only skim the least worst off
of the low-income households for assistance. Still other definitions may seek
a mixing of a full range of households by income including those below poverty
(less than 30 percent of the AMFI) with those who are the working poor (30 to
80 percent of the AMFI) with those who are middle- or upper-income (above 80
percent of AMFI).
The published research on mixed-income housing makes it clear that the concept
of mixing households by income goes beyond income alone. In these efforts, the
goal is to mix low-income families with children with other families. In some
efforts, the notion of mixed-income housing involves the employment status of
the residents. Here the goal is to mix low-income households who suffer from
chronic unemployment with households who are gainfully employed in steady jobs.
Still other efforts merge the concept of mixed-income housing with mixed occupancy
across racial and ethnic groups.
Some research has narrowed the scope of mixed-income housing. This research
has, for example, sought to limit the definition of mixed-income housing to
just rental housing (Wilkins 2001). Given the higher incidence of low-income
households among the renter population, this narrowing of the definition is
not without justification. However, many low-income owner occupants exist, and
successful programs to serve their integration into a mixed-income housing setting
exist to serve the needs of these households.
Benefits of Mixed-Income Housing
The concept of mixed-income housing is gaining in popularity, in some measure,
due to the problems found in developments serving only low-income households.
The high incidence of crime, unemployment, drug usage and other social problems
resulting from concentrations of poverty are more than enough to cause people
to search for new alternatives to housing developments that concentrate poverty.
The benefits of mixed-income housing have been found in several areas.
Impact upon adults. Mixing households from different income levels is meant
to provide social interaction so as to reduce the culture of poverty associated
with concentrated poverty. Here the notion is that low-income households can
gain from living and interacting with households who are employed and exhibit
the work ethic so often missing in areas of concentrated poverty. It is well
known that finding employment requires more than just physical proximity to
the jobs; it requires membership in the network through which open positions
are announced, applied for and filled. The hope is that the interaction between
neighbors of mixed-income housing can facilitate bringing low-income persons
into the network providing information and access to employment and out of poverty.
However, research by Brophy and Smith (1997) suggest that employment gains among
formerly unemployed low-income adults are very much a function of intensive
job training and job placement program associated with the housing assistance.
Simply offering mixed-income housing without additional social welfare programs
will not generate the significant employment gains that are expected.
Reducing the culture of poverty means more than just assisting the poor in finding
employment. It seeks to improve the conduct of the low-income residents. If
non-working adults and their children live in a setting dominated by working
families, the poor are less likely to participate in anti-social conduct than
would be the case when living in a development with concentrated poverty (MHC
2001). Even if the direct interaction between the residents of a mixed-income
development is minimal, the change in conduct should provide benefits simply
from the improved expectations for that conduct.
Impact upon children. Mixing households from different income levels is also
meant to provide social interaction among children. Children raised in areas
of concentrated poverty may suffer from the absence of role models who are regularly
employed. Children from families with chronic unemployment should benefit from
attending the same school as children with families who are working (MHC 2001).
Having children attend schools with children from a full array of income levels
will increase social interaction. It is also hoped that the culture of poverty
can be removed for low-income children through this interaction.
The impact of mixed-income housing upon children may well go beyond the classroom.
There is evidence that children need role models. Mixed-income communities permit
children to grow up in a social setting where working for a living is the norm
among adults. If children are not exposed to working adult role models early
in life, it decreases the probability that as adults these individuals will
be able to gain and hold regular employment (Wilkins 2001).
Impact on abutting properties. The research indicates that benefits from mixed-income
housing may well be economic as well as sociological. A great debate has been
waged over a long period of time examining whether or not assisted housing has
a detrimental effect upon abutting properties. It is safe to say that no consensus
has been reached on this issue. Research can be found for all possible answers.
Some research finds that assisted housing has a detrimental effect upon abutting
properties. Some research finds that assisted housing has a positive effect
upon abutting properties. Still other research finds no relationship between
assisted housing and abutting properties (Lee at al 2000). Wherever the truth
may lie, mixed-income housing is likely to calm the debate. Projects containing
only a small portion of units for low-income households with the remainder of
the units offered at market-rate prices can reduce the risk of negative impact
upon the neighborhood by lowering the value of abutting properties (MHC 2001).
Political benefits. Anyone who has worked in the field of affordable housing
is painfully familiar with the word NIMBY, Not In My Back Yard.
Existing residents of a neighborhood will often oppose the development of affordable
housing in their midst. While asserting that they are not opposed to the development
of low-income housing, they simply do not want it in their neighborhood. The
motivation for this attitude is difficult to discern. It may be motivated by
a class attitude where the middle-class do not want encroachment into their
neighborhood by the poor. It may be motivated by fear of loss of value, based
upon the belief that the presence of the low-income housing will reduce the
value of the middle-class housing. It may be motivated by fear, a concern that
the low-income residents will introduce new or increased crime into the neighborhood.
Developers of housing know about these fears and the difficulties of developing
housing, whether these difficulties result from zoning issues, financing issues
or management issues. Adding a number of low-income units to a development making
it into mixed-income housing can increase the degree of difficulty that a developer
confronts in making the development feasible. However, the difficulties gained
by the inclusion of units for low-income households can be outweighed by the
reductions in the NIMBY attitudes (U. Cincinnati 1999). Opposition to the development
of housing can be lessened if the development is mixed-income rather than entirely
low-income. As is so often the case, the details matter. If a mixed-income development
is dominated by market-rate occupancy and the design and construction of the
development meets local market standards, the likelihood of opposition is reduced.
Political costs. Ironically, the shift from low-income housing toward mixed-income
housing may engender opposition by advocates of housing for the low-income (U.
of Cincinnati 1999). This may manifest itself either as an objection to the
incursion of middle-income households into an area previously dominated by low-income
households, or it may take the form of a budget battle over the use of funds.
Displacement of low-income households is always a matter of concern in areas
experiencing gentrification. As older neighborhoods once populated by low-income
households become fashionable for middle-income households, the natural market
process raises the price of housing in these neighborhoods for all households,
rich and poor alike. This can displace the poor who are unable, given their
limited means, to pay the higher prices being charged for the housing after
gentrification. Advocates for the poor actively oppose this gentrification process
and may view the development of mixed-income housing as encouraging the gentrification
process rather than protecting the poor from its harmful effects.
Older central cities typically see a need to attract middle-class residents
back to the central city, reversing the capital flight toward the suburbs that
has taken its toll on cities for so many years. Any strategy that has the potential
to attract the middle-class back to the neighborhoods that have become dominated
by the poor will be seen as an effective strategy for the city. Despite a backlash
by the advocates for the poor, cities will value the increased properties values
and household income that the mixed-income housing can generate.
Opposition to mixed-income housing can also take the form of simple arguments
over budget priorities. Funding for housing assistance can be viewed as a zero-sum
game; any diversion of funding for low-income housing into any other initiative
can be seen as a loss for the low-income. Some advocates for housing for the
poor see mixed-income housing as competing with low-income housing for available
scarce resources. However, the subsidy mechanism is structured, the concern
is that any use of housing assistance for mixed-income housing sends dollars
away from the poor and toward the middle-income. This diversion away from the
more needy low-income toward the middle-income is deemed to be a reduction in
the redistribution goals of assisted housing (Rosenbaum et al 1998). At the
extreme, advocates argue that scarce housing dollars should serve the poorest
of the poor, and only the poorest of the poor.
Programmatic benefits. Mixed-income housing may hold promise for correcting
some of the problems now being experienced with existing housing programs. Section
8 Housing Choice Vouchers now represent the nations largest housing assistance
program. Over 1.5 million households receive help in paying their housing costs
through the program. This program was designed to make maximum use of existing
housing in the marketplace. At its most simplistic level, the program pays the
difference between what a household can afford to spend on housing (about 30
percent of its income) and the cost of occupying that housing. This form of
assistance is supposed to permit a low-income household to surmount the price
barriers that restrict the housing choices of the poor. With the Section 8 assistance,
the argument goes, the household can move into any good quality housing that
is reasonably priced within the marketplace.
Unfortunately, the Section 8 program has not been able to perform as expected.
Section 8 recipient households are not dispersed across the nations metropolitan
areas, rather they tend to be concentrated into areas with high levels of poverty
(Leger and Kennedy 1990). The law does not required landlords to accept Section
8 vouchers. This has had a limiting effect upon the spatial distribution of
Section 8 assistance. Landlords with units available in desirable neighborhoods
with high income levels, good schools and ample services will enjoy adequate
demand for their units without having to accept Section 8 vouchers. Landlords
with units available in undesirable neighborhoods with low income levels, poor
schools and few or no services may have to actively seek Section 8 as one of
the few ways to find a reliable revenue source for their properties.
Mixed-income housing has shown the potential to correct this problem. The nations
largest program to assist in the development of housing for occupancy by the
low-income is the Low-Income Housing Tax Credit program. This program has demonstrated
both a capacity to be used for mixed-income applications and the capacity to
make entry into suburban middle-income areas where Section 8 seems to be unable
to locate (McClure 2001). Despite the presumed ease of use and lower-cost associated
with a voucher approach to assisting the poor, the Section 8 voucher program
is not breaking down the barriers to economic integration of the poor. Instead,
the more costly LIHTC program is demonstrating that mixed-income assisted rental
properties can do a better job of providing units for the low-income in neighborhoods
low-income households are not otherwise present.
There is also hope that mixed-income housing has the potential to improve
the quality of the stock of assisted housing. Public housing and other forms
of assisted housing are often viewed as housing that has not been maintained
in good condition, at least in part, due to the absence of market discipline.
Mixed-income housing, by definition, is housing that has a portion of its units
offered to the market at whatever price the market will bear. This creates pressure
on the part of developers and property managers to keep the housing competitive
within the market so that the units can capture their share of the market demand
(MHC 2001).
Political Antecedents
The concept of market failure has long dominated the formation of housing policy.
The concept argues that government should not intervene into private markets
if the private markets are functioning well on their own. The corollary is that
government intervention is only justifiable only if the market is failing to
function properly. This raises the question can mixed-income housing happen
on its own? The answer is that yes it can, and it does occur in many settings.
Khadduri and Martin (1997) find that more than one quarter of unassisted poor
renters living in the nations metropolitan areas live in census tracts
where the population is less than 10 percent poor. This suggests that income
mixing is more than norm than the exception. However, this mixing may reflect
more of a mixing of incomes among households headed by workers than a mixing
of working and non-working households, not the mixing of the non-working poor
into the mainstream population.
The non-working poor tend to be concentrated into specific neighborhoods within
our urban areas, and assisted low-income housing may be exacerbating this problem.
Newman and Schnare (1997) find that the probability of living in a neighborhood
with social ills increases among poor households who reside in assisted housing.
This is because the assisted housing is not located throughout the metropolitan
areas of the nation; rather, the assisted housing tends to be concentrated in
areas with high incidences of poverty and unemployment. Recognizing the problems
of concentrated poverty and HUDs own inadvertent contribution to this
concentration, HUD has responded by favoring mixed-income housing in many of
its assisted housing initiatives
Among the most direct of efforts to further mixed-income housing is the HOPE
VI program. This program restructures the ownership, management and occupancy
of troubled public housing projects. Prior to HOPE VI, these troubled housing
projects were owned and managed by the local housing authority with occupancy
only for the poorest of the poor. After the HOPE VI intervention, the property
comes under new ownership that is typically a partnership between private sector
developers and the housing authority. Frequently, the partnership involves the
participation of local non-profit community development organizations. The new
partnership renovates the property and markets it to a new set of tenants who
are a mixture of the low-income households previously found in the projects
plus moderate- and middle-income households. This program has received $4.5
billion dollars over the last 10 years, but the most recent budget message from
the White House calls of discontinuation of the program.
HUD has also taken steps to transform the Section 8 Housing Choice Voucher program.
The recipient household of the Section 8 voucher continues to have the power
to select the location for the housing. However, as part of the Section 8 Management
Assessment Program (SEMAP), HUD evaluates the administrators of Section 8 housing
programs in terms of how well they are able to guide households away from areas
of concentrated poverty and into areas with lower levels of poverty. Through
this SEMAP process, HUD is demonstrating its bias toward deconcentration of
impoverished households and toward mixing assisted households by income level.
Although not under the control of HUD, the Low-Income Housing Tax Credit program
has demonstrated its capacity to serve not only developments designed as low-income
projects but mixed-income projects as well (McClure 2000). While always planned
as a program to subsidize the develop of either mixed-income or only low-income
units, the early years of the program witnessed a tendency for most developments
to be 100 percent low-income occupancy. Few developments had any significant
level of market-rate units in the mix. However, in recent years, the trend has
been toward mixed-income housing. Individual states have changed their Qualified
Allocation Plans to guide the allocation of tax credits among competing development
proposals. The plans now favor mixed-income housing where it is feasible. In
addition, the revenue that can be raised from the sale of tax credits has increased
over time. This results in fewer units within a development needing to be subsidized
with tax credits in order for a development to attain financial feasibility.
In addition, in 1994 a procedure was adopted to compel states to review all
development proposals ensuring that no more tax credits are awarded to a development
than are minimally to bring it to financial feasibility. Finally, LIHTC developments
have become mainstream. No longer are these developments associated only with
impoverished areas of older central cities, they are now found in the suburbs
sitting side by side with market rate developments. All of these trends favor
the development of mixed-income housing rather than just low-income housing.
Can these efforts to create mixed-income housing succeed? Joseph E. Corcoran
(2002) heads the prominent Boston-based property development and management
firm CMJ Management. The firm has developed mixed-income housing throughout
the Boston area. Corcoran states, Everyonebankers, U.S. Department
of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) officials, representatives of local and
state agencies, and, particularly, other builderstrashed the concept.
They said that it would never work. Market-rate households will never
live with subsidized households. Corcoran has proved them wrong.
Mixed-income housing is operational throughout the nation. Many progressive
cities require new developments to make some provision for low-income households.
In Boston, Mayor Thomas M. Menino has adopted a policy that requires all proposals
for new luxury housing projects to include at least 10 percent affordable units.
The Millennial Housing Commission, a bipartisan taskforce appointed by Congress
to study affordable housing problems and to recommend future policy directions
for the federal government. The Millennial Housing Commission has come to the
position that failing to further mixed-income housing is too risky. The Commission
states,
Some argue that, because of the severity of the adverse consequences
of concentrated-poverty properties, it is good public policy to pursue mixed-income
approaches even if it cannot be convincingly demonstrated that mixed income
approaches are superior. A variant of this argument is that mixed income approaches
must be pursued vigorously even though we may not know exactly how to make
them work well consistently, because the chance that we will not discover
how to make mixed income approaches work is outweighed by the near certainty
of failure if we continue to pursue concentrated-poverty approaches.
Market Conditions Necessary for Mixed-Income Housing
Can mixed-income housing work anywhere? The body of research on this topic suggests
that the answer is no. Some housing markets are well suited to the successful
mixing of assisted households across a broad range of income levels. Some housing
markets are less well suited. This means that planners must learn when and where
successful mixed-income housing developments can come into being.
The Millennial Housing Commission offers a word of caution.
It must be said that mixed income housing runs contrary to the very
prevalent though not universal tendency of Americans to segregate
themselves by income. It is therefore not surprising that mixed income housing
requires care in design and operation, in order to succeed.
A tight housing market. One factor has been recognized as contributing to the
success of mixed-income housing, and this is a tight housing market. Khadduri
and Martin found, in their examination of several mixed-income housing developments,
that the successful projects tend to be located in housing markets characterized
by strong demand for housing and low vacancy rates. Mixed-income housing can
be seen as a positive, a negative or a neutral attribute of a housing development.
If housing is scarce, more households will be willing to take up residence where
low-income households are part of the mix. This suggests that mixed-income housing
is not seen as a positive attribute of a development. If households searching
for housing are indifferent to the income mix in a development, then there should
be no relationship between the housing market conditions and the presence of
mixed-income housing. Households would locate in the housing based upon factors
other than mix of incomes in the property. If households searching for housing
view mixing of incomes as a positive attribute, then they would seek out such
developments, whether the market is tight or soft. However, only if households
view mixing of incomes as a negative attribute would market tightness be a factor.
Households seeking housing appear to be willing to accept mixed-income housing
where it is part of a trade-off. They are trading the mixed-income attributes
of the development (a negative attribute) for the housing that is otherwise
hard to find in the tight market (a positive attribute). As long as consumers
continue to view mixed-income developments as less desirable than developments
that contain only a single strata of the income distribution, the pressure will
be on developers, property managers and marketing agents to make the mixed income
housing sufficiently attractive so as to overcome this market-based preference.
If a market is not tight, instead vacancy rates are normal and prices stable,
what type of housing market will be suitable for mixed-income housing? It is
apparent from the published research that mixed-income housing needs to be located
in desirable markets. This means a viable neighborhood with low poverty rates,
good schools, low crime rates, and good access to jobs, shopping and other community
services.
Poverty and crime rates in the market. Khadduri and Martin go further in their
assessment of the market conditions where mixed-income housing succeeds. They
find that most privately owned, mixed-income rental housing developments assisted
by HUD are not located in high-poverty neighborhoods. Exceptions may exist.
The authors suggestsadmittedly with only limited datathat a market
can have a very high incidence of poverty and still be able to attract middle-income
households if, for example, the neighborhood is characterized by an upwardly
mobile set of immigrants who are using the assisted housing and a gateway to
full participation in the community. Another version of this exception may be
the gentrifying area where the market has become appealing to a new set of residents
who are willing to accept the risks of living in the area in exchange for the
special locational or architectural features provided by the mixed-income housing.
Absent such special circumstances, it does not appear that mixed-income housing
is likely to succeed if the neighborhood suffers from widespread poverty. This
is equally true of crime rates. Mixed-income housing is unlikely to succeed
if located in areas suffering from high crime rates. While it is unfortunate
that the mixed-income approach to assisted housing does not seem to work well
in all market settings, experience suggests that for a mixed-income development
to be successful, it must be located where only a small share of the markets
population falls below poverty and where crime rates are relatively low.
What attracts higher income renters? Brophy and Smith address this issue directly.
They find that good location, attractive design features, and effective management
are all essential to attracting higher income households. The upper-income households
have relatively more options in the marketplace compared to their low-income
counterparts. Given this greater array of choices, the mixed-income housing
must offer amenities and a quality of living that is competitive with or exceeding
what is found elsewhere. This means the mixed-income housing must offer close
proximity and easy access to the employment and shopping that all the residents
need. The curb appeal must be high enough to make the residents
want to live there. Finally, the residents must have confidence that the property
managers will maintain the property in good shape over time so that all residents,
but especially the upper-income residents who can more readily relocate, will
want to continue to reside in the development.
The importance of schools. One of the often-voiced benefits of mixed-income
housing is the interaction between poor children who may be lacking sufficient
role models in their lives and other residents of the developments. To the extent
that all of the children attend the same schools, this interaction can occur
in the classroom. However, research suggests that the interaction found in schools
may be largely limited to the classroom. The higher income households who choose
to reside in mixed-income developments tend to have fewer children or no children
compared than the low-income residents (MHC 2001). This means that to fully
engage the children of low-income households into the social interaction hoped
for in mixed-income housing, it is necessary to attract upper-income households
with children to these developments.
Schools are an extremely important determinant of the desirability of a housing
development. Mixed-income developments in an area served by poor quality schools
will encounter great difficulty attracting significant numbers of upper-income
households with children (Wilkins 2001). These upper-income households have
many options in terms of their housing choices, and these households will not
sacrifice the quality of their childrens education just to participate
in a mixed-income housing development. This suggests that the success of mixed-income
housing is very dependent upon the quality of the schools serving the housing.
In fact, the MHC report suggests that unless the schools serving the development
are particularly high, there is little chance of being able to sustain any significant
percentage of upper-income households in the development.
Selecting neighborhoods. At is most simplistic level, if a mixed-income development
is located in a desirable neighborhood with low poverty rates, good schools,
negligible crime, attractive architectural or historical features, and with
good proximity to jobs and shopping, it is likely to be successful. If the property
is located in a troubled neighborhood, it is likely to fail (MHC 2001). The
MHC recommends that mixed-income housing should not be attempted in high-poverty
areas except where the housing development is part of a widespread neighborhood
revitalization effort with intensive management and social welfare programs
covering both housing and non-housing services.
If the plan is to generate mixed-income housing in a troubled neighborhood,
that plan must accommodate significantly increased total development costs (MHC
2001). In order to fund the intensive support programs that are needed and to
provide attractive prices to higher-income households, significant subsidies
will be needed to write down the costs of development. In addition, the scale
of the development must be sufficiently large to have a significant impact upon
the character of the neighborhood.
The Ideal Mix of Occupants
Mixing by income level. One very clear message is found in the research on mixed-income
housing, the occupancy by low-income households must be no more than a minority
of the households in the development. The research speaks to a need for a critical
mass of upper-income households who must dominate the development in order to
maintain the character of the development as mixed-income development.
The research also suggests that the management of the mix is critical to the
success of the development. The suggestion is that if the mixed-income development
is perceived as another low-income development, with all of the problems associated
with low-income projects, then the development is doomed to failure. Brophy
and Smith report on the Harbor Point development in Boston, an early and much
contested mixed-income development created out of a troubled public housing
project. They found that, after redevelopment, one section of the development
began occupancy with a relatively high percentage of non-working poor families.
This section quickly became entirely non-working poor households due to the
unwillingness of the higher-income working households to live in this section
of the development with its impoverished nor-working environment. This demonstrates
the skill needed by the management to carefully arrange for the occupancy of
the development in such a way as to avoid the kind of problems that can transpire
even within a development.
A formal agreement must usually exist between the property owners and the providers
of the subsidy funding specifying the level of low-income and upper-income occupancy
that is to be maintained in the development over time. At the very minimum,
such an agreement is need to ensure that the number of low-income households
in the development does not fall below the expected minimum. However, the Millennial
Housing Commission argues for flexibility in the agreement. Management needs
some latitude in its operation in order work around and to remedy problems such
as those encountered in Bostons Harbor Point development. Rigid percentages
specifying the income levels of the tenant population can be hard to achieve
over time. The key to successfully maintaining a healthy mix of incomes in any
development is to secure high quality management who can be trusted to serve
the goal of mixed-income occupancy but adjust to periodic shifts in the demand
for the housing. Markets and neighborhoods change over time. Rigid occupancy
requirements can fail to grant the necessary maneuverability to property managers
and marketing agents.
The Millennial Housing Commission suggests that the percentage of low-income
households in a mixed-income development should be about 15 to 20 percent of
the total. MHC suggests that, A mix with more than 20% non-working families
should be attempted only with a very experienced sponsor, with a qualified and
experienced management team, and with significantly more intensive management.
Experience suggests that keeping the percentage of non-working poor families
at or below 20 percent is necessary to maintain the mixed-income character of
the property. However, evidence exists that occupancy mixes containing 20 to
40 percent non-working poor families can succeed but only if very intensively
managed in just the right market settings.
Khadduri and Martin agree. They find that a number of owners and managers have
reached a commonly held opinion that a mix of 15 to 20 percent non-working low-income
families in an otherwise working-family property is likely to be feasible if
managed competently. Higher proportions of non-working families are likely to
threaten the feasibility of the development and demand even greater levels of
management involvement. Greater than 40 percent occupancy by non-working poor
families is a very high risk strategy. This approach should be attempted only
under the most promising circumstances, such as a property owner and manager
who has a lengthy track record of success with a very similar property.
Disparity in the income distribution. Ironically, the smaller the disparity
between the lowest and the highest income levels, the higher the level of success.
Brophy and Smith find a high incidence of problems between householdsincluding
vandalism of cars by low-income teenagersin properties with relatively
large disparities between the incomes of the non-working families and the incomes
of the working households. Alternatively, the properties that maintained a significant
level of moderate-income occupants, social tensions appeared to be less frequent,
even if some higher income households reside at the property. There suggests
that the social benefits of income mixing may not be automatic.
A very wide range of incomes may be more difficult to achieve and maintain than
a modest range of incomes. In particular, a wide gap between the very low-income
and higher-income groups is likely to be counterproductive. Brophy and Smith
find that at some point when the gap between the income of the lowest and highest
earning households become too large, this gap becomes a source of envy, resentment,
and tension, rather than a source of encouragement for self-improvement. This
problem of resentment can be mitigated by having the occupancy cover a full
range of incomes from low, to moderate, to high. Brophy and Smith suggest that
a mix which more closely mirrors the income mix of the local population will
draw the most political support necessary to make the project feasible.
Design of the units. One final factor in the design of the income mix involves
the design the housing units themselves. The research argues that the units
should all look the same. The low-income units must be identical to the units
offered to the middle- and upper-income households. This issue furthers the
argument for flexibility in the powers given to the management team. In an ideal
setting, all the housing units are the same, and only the property manager or
the marketing agent knows which households are low-income and which households
are not. This approach avoids the stigma that seems to go with low-income units.
In a development for owner-occupancy, only the marketing agents know the incomes
of the households purchasing the properties. In rental developments, only the
property managers know which tenants meet the low-income requirements and which
are in market-rate units.
Mixing by race and ethnicity. HUDs research suggests that racial and ethnic
diversity may not be a factor in predicting the success of mixed-income housing.
From their study of privately owned but federally subsidized apartment properties,
Khadduri and Martin find that housing with a resident population that is diverse
in terms of race and ethnicity has only a modest effect on the likelihood of
having a widely mixed incomes as housing in which one racial or ethnic group
predominates. This modest effect is, in fact positive. If the project has a
racially or ethnically diverse population, it is slightly more likely to have
a diverse range of incomes. While creating and maintaining mixed-income housing
is a challenge, this research suggests that integrating this mixed-income housing
along racial or ethnic lines will not present any significant additional problems.
Joseph Corcoran (2002) speaks about his extensive experience in developing racially
and ethnically diverse housing developments:
Racially mixing all income groups also is important, and we make a concerted
outreach effort to do so. Harbor Point is home to 3,000 people living in 1,283
units. Thirty-five percent of the market-rate units are inhabited by members
of minority groups, 20 percent of whom are African American. Twenty percent
of the low-income families are white. Our marketing and social service staff
works hard to achieve this mix, by reaching out to local employers, community
centers and publications, government agencies, and even elected officials. For
example, in urban public housing turnaround projects, in which African American
and Hispanic families typically dominate the low-income component, our on-site
social service workers go to low-income, nonprofit agencies and offer our units
to white families on housing wait lists. In suburban mixed-income communities,
we do the reverse. Our marketing staff also visits corporate human services
departments and actively markets market-rate units to minority workers, stressing
our objective of creating racially mixed communities.
Racial and ethnic mixing can be achieved as well as income mixing, but it will
not happened without a concerted effort on the part of the property developer
and manager. Efforts must be focused and ongoing. Outreach to social service
agencies must be made and maintained.
Approaches to Promoting Mixed-Income Housing
Too often the concept of mixed-income housing has been narrowly constrained
to multi-family rental housing developments. While this remains an important
form of mixed-income housing, it is only one among many. Efforts to foster mixed-income
housing can follow may paths.
Owners and renters. Mixed-income housing can provide housing for either owner-occupants
or renters. The developments served do not need to be just rental developments;
they can be any of many types of owner-occupied housing, whether in the form
of condominiums in multi-family structures or as owner-occupants of single-family
units.
Single parcels and scattered-sites. The mixed-income housing can be on a single
land parcel or can be spread across multiple sites. Whether a single contiguous
site or several non-contiguous parcels, the goal is to create close interaction
between people of different economic strata. This can be accomplished on one
or many sites. The scattered sites approach can work by providing housing opportunities
for low-income households in otherwise low poverty neighborhoods. Research has
shown this to be a successful approach in urban as well as more rural settings.
The social interaction that generates the benefits of mixed-income housing can
be achieved at the neighborhood level if sufficient contacts can happen between
the occupants of the newly developed scattered-site housing and the existing
residents of the neighborhood. Unfortunately, experience with scattered-site
public housing is not encouraging. Briggs (1999) study of scattered-site
housing suggests that identifiable low-income buildings, even if containing
only four units and located inside of neighborhoods with low levels of poverty,
the social isolation of low-income households survives. The social interaction
sought through mixed-income housing is not achieved.
Scattered-site housing is widely recognized to generate higher operating expenses.
Managing, maintaining and insuring properties over several sites is more expensive
than if the housing were to be located on a single parcel. This means that the
planners who pursue this approach must recognize this cost premium and provide
for it.
While the scattered-site is capable of working well, the research makes it evident
that dangers exist. Depending upon the setting, scattered-site developments
usually take the form of small buildings located within existing neighborhoods.
The residents of the neighborhood are generally aware that the scattered-site
dwellings are assisted and to be occupied by low-income households. This knowledge
can cause all of the political opposition so often confronted with any low-income
housing development. Even individual buildings of small scale will not lessen
the opposition. If one of the goals of mixed-income housing is to reduce the
stigma associated with living in a low-income project, then scattered-site buildings
may accomplish little more than exporting the stigma from large low-income projects
that often comprise their own neighborhoods into smaller buildings that may
be unwelcome in otherwise low-poverty neighborhoods.
New construction, rehabilitation or existing housing. The housing in question
can be of many types. It can be newly constructed. It can be existing housing
that is rehabilitated for new occupancy. It can be existing housing leased or
purchased for new occupancy with little or no construction work included in
the mixed-income initiative.
Regulatory requirements. The style of government intervention may vary across
applications. The government may hope to stimulate the development of mixed-income
housing from a regulatory approach. Here the government may require the inclusion
of mixed-income housing in all new developments through restrictions imposed
through the zoning and subdivision regulations.
Subsidy mechanisms. Alternatively, the government may provide financial incentives
in an effort to entice developers and property owners to participate in various
mixed-income housing initiatives. The subsidy mechanisms used to development
the mixed-income housing may take many forms. The subsidy may be attached to
the dwelling unit, following the more traditional project-based approach to
assisted housing. The subsidy may instead be attached to the household. The
assistance may be designed to help specific households consume housing that
furthers the goal of income mixing.
Vouchers can be used to give low-income households entrance to housing that
would otherwise be available only to working families. The attractiveness of
Section 8 vouchers as a means to achieve mixed-income housing is that the property
owner continues to obtain market-rate rents on the units even if occupied by
a low-income household. The government pays the differential between what the
low-income household can afford and what the market will pay for the unit. Unfortunately,
Section 8, as previously noted, has not fostered a great deal of movement by
the poor out of areas with concentrated poverty and into areas with low levels
of poverty. Property owners often refuse to accept Section 8 when offered. Property
owners and managers recommend significant reforms to the voucher program in
order to make this approach viable. Problems most frequently mentioned include
the revising the local payment standard, adjusting the rent reasonableness test,
the lease terms, the timeliness of inspections, and timeliness and accuracy
of payments (MHC 2001).
Some have argued for mixed-income within the context of housing developments
that are fully covered by Section 8. Khadduri and Martin have examined such
configurations with at least 20 percent of the occupants having incomes that
are above $20,000 per year placing them in the category of modest income or
working poor and at least 20 percent of the occupants having income under $10,000
per year placing them below poverty. Here the goal is less one of mixing across
a full range of incomes and more one of mixing across those who are gainfully
employed and those who are not. Khadduri and Martin suggest that this can be
a productive approach if the dominant share of the households in the development
have wages as their primary source of income.
Use of existing federal subsidy programs. Some existing programs are well suited
to applications to mixed-income housing. HOPE VI directs the bulk of its funds
toward mixed-income housing. Section 8 Housing Choice Vouchers can be utilized
in a variety of settings beyond the conventional rental assistance approach.
Section 8 can be used as a project-based form of assistance. Section 8 can be
tied to various welfare-to-work initiatives which can make mixed-income housing
part of the package. Section 8 can be implemented with local preferences to
guide households to mixed-income neighborhoods. CBDG and HOME funds can also
be used in creative ways to further the cause of mixed-income housing.
Low-Income Housing Tax Credits can be a very effective tool for the development
of mixed-income housing. The LIHTC program is changing over time. When first
created, the program was able to leverage only a little over 42 cents on the
dollar of credit awarded. Now it is commonplace for projects for receive over
70 cents on the dollar of credit awarded. This increase in leverage means a
shift away from developments that are 100 percent covered by tax credits and
toward developments that have only a portion of their units covered. Those units
that are not covered by tax credits are offered at market rates. Thus, a by-product
of the increasing leverage of the LIHTC program is the shift toward mixed-income
housing.
Skewed rents. The inclusion of market-rate units in a LIHTC development (or
any other form of mixed-income rental property) raises the issue of skewed rents.
Skewed rents have many meanings. For purposes of mixed-income housing concerns,
skewed rents usually mean lower rents on the market-rate units than would otherwise
be paid in the market if the development contained no low-income households.
The Millennial Housing Commission asked if higher-income households should receive
a rent that is below the market level? The answer is yes. The argument of the
downward skewing of rents for higher-income households is to attract the higher-income
household to the development. If the household who can afford to live elsewhere
is going to be attracted to the mixed-income setting, then a lower price is
the logical form of an inducement. Brophy and Smith report that several of the
seven properties they studied offered rents below the rents that the property
could command in the market. They conclude that this rent discount is essential
for properties to be successful in attracting and retaining the higher income
residents. The argument is made that the economic incentive of the lower rent
must be larger and larger the more the development is seeking to attract the
upper-income household to live in lower-income neighborhoods. To the extent
that the mixed-income housing is in an otherwise low-poverty neighborhood, then
the reduction in rent for the higher-income household may be very small.
Shallow subsidy. One last subsidy mechanism used leverage mixed-income housing
has been the use of below market interest rate financing subsidies. These subsidies
are deemed shallow in that they do not provide the extensive, or deep, level
of subsidy provided through the LIHTC program, which heavily subsidizes development
costs, or the Section 8 program, which heavily subsidizes the income stream
of a development. The shallow subsidies usually take the form of below market
interest rate financing. The developer of the property obtains a break in the
interest rate on the debt. This lowers the costs of financing which makes it
possible to accept lower rents on a small percentage of the units in the development.
This approach has been used successfully by state housing finance agencies to
develop mixed-income housing. The state agencies are able to provide the below
market financing by passing through to the developer the lower interest rate
paid on tax-exempt debt (Schwartz and Tajbakhsh 1997).
Management and Marketing
The research on mixed-income housing offers almost as much information on the
management of this specialized type of housing as it does on its development.
The managers of these properties must possess skills beyond those normally expected
of property managers. They must engage in programs usually associated with social
workers and case managers. These managers should be able to expect compensation
commensurate with this skill level and workload and should be extended the trust
necessary to carry out their mission.
Skill level necessary. The MHC warns planners to pay attention to the selection
of a management agent for mixed-income housing. This specialized form of housing
makes greater demands upon the property managers demanding more experience among
the management staff and more intensive management programs. In the MHCs
terms, Evidence from mixed income communities suggests that there is powerful
public benefit in having not merely adequate but excellent management.
Corcoran agrees but suggests that in order to succeed--even with these skills--property
managers should apply rules uniformly to all residents whether low-income or
upper-income. The management should avoid income-segregated buildings or areas
within the development. Income mixing should exist throughout the development;
no identifiable buildings or areas should be identifiable as having low-income
occupancy. Rather, the skill is found in the property mangers ability to enforce
rules and demand a high standard of conduct throughout the property. This, MHC
indicates, is essential for a property to be successful.
Intensive programs expected. Experience in mixed-income developments demonstrates,
unequivocally, that simply placing households together in a mixed-income setting
is not enough to generate the positive social outcomes planned. Intensive social
programs must be a part of the management plan. Only when management engages
in significant non-housing programs will the mixed-income housing succeed. These
programs include job training, job placement, childcare, general education degree
programs, computer training, plus before- and after-school activities. The programs
must also command adherence to high standards of resident conduct. Funding for
these programs must either be found externally or their costs built into the
operating expenses of the development.
Compensations expected and trust extended. Property managers in mixed-income
housing will need to be compensated for the higher skill level that they must
possess. It is important to recognize that managing mixed-income developments
are more difficult than managing developments that are all market-rate. This
difficulty factor must be acknowledged in the management plan and the management
fees paid must compensate for it.
Trust managers to carry out the mission: If the property managers are to be
given greater challenges and greater fees than their counter-parts in market-rate
development, experience suggests that they should also be given greater trust.
This trust takes the form of discretionary power to manage the property so as
to achieve the goals of mixed-income housing. The temptation is to have the
property manager work under a rigid plan calling for fixed percentages of households
for each of the targeted income strata. The MHC has examined this trend and
finds it ill advised. Instead, the MHC calls for flexibility for the property
managers. Decisions about the desired mix of tenants should be set as goals
for the property manger, and the manager should be evaluated periodically for
its performance in achieving these goals. However, the day-to-day decisions
concerning who should be placed in a specific unit need to be left to the manager.
Rigid rules can hinder, rather than help, efforts to create a successful development.
In addition, the surrounding market conditions can change and change rapidly.
Property managers need to have the freedom to adjust their management practices
as the market around them changes.
This flexibility also carries over into marketing a development or property.
The best marketing strategy for mixed-income developments will vary from property
to property. Even the degree to which the property is marketed as a mixed-income
development has been found to vary. Brophy and Smith report that the seven properties
they studied mentioned the mixed-income nature of the community but did not
emphasize it. If the upper-income households are receiving a below market rent,
the mixed-income character of the development is generally not a marketing disadvantage.
In some communities the mixed-income character of the community may become the
primary attraction offered in the marketing approach. Mixed-income developments
may be particularly attractive to certain upper-income households who value
a mixed-income development and want to live in such a community. In select markets
with significant numbers of households holding these values, marketing the mixed-income
nature of the development becomes a viable marketing strategy. MHC found that
owners and managers report that individual markets vary in their receptiveness
to mixed-income approaches. Areas that had positive experience with affordable
housing responded favorably to mixed-income housing.
Cases
Below are a few examples of effective efforts toward mixed-income housing:
Case: Langham Court
South End, Boston, Massachusetts
Type: New construction, mixed-income, 84 units.
Background: Very tight housing market in Bostons South End driving
demand.
The original plan was to mix condominiums with rentals. That plan was changed
to a limited-dividend co-operative, demonstrating the need for flexibility
in management and marketing. Property managers worked with residents encouraging
participation in events so that neighbors can meet.
Design: The design employs features found in the historic South End. This
includes textured brick, dormer windows, vaulted entries, a mixture of mansard
and flat roof, and a scale that fits area buildings.
The south-facing courtyard provides a sunny landscaped retreat for all residents.
During the community design process, neighbors expressed an interest in a
public park on the street. The development team eventually convinced the community
that the open park would be a security and maintenance problem. The interior
courtyard is visible from the street and is used by both Langham residents
and the low-income senior residents of the adjacent Washington Manor apartments.
Management: There are approximately 40 children of all age groups, and they
are the main users of the courtyard. The courtyard is U-shaped and well positioned
for good observation from both the managers office and many of the apartments.
Langham Court exemplifies the success of mixed income housing, a model in
which the housing for all income levels must aspire to high standards to minimize
a sense of hierarchy within the development. As ten year old Blanca Hernandez
wrote in a winning essay sponsored by the National Council of State Housing
Agencies, " I 'specially like living in Langham Court because where I
used to live it was a bad neighborhood with drugs everywhere. Here, I really
don't see drugs, and it's a good neighborhood, and I can play outside and
sleep without worry."
Case: Lake Parc Place
Chicago
Type: Restructured public housing into mixed-income rental housing
Subsidy: Financial incentives to new partnership.
Background: Lake Park Place is an experiment in creating mixed-income housing
in buildings that were previously low-income public housing owned by the Chicago
Housing Authority.
Reduced rents are offered to households whose income is too high to qualify
for low-income housing.
Studied by Rosenbaum (Rosenbaum et al 1998) through a large survey. Study
finds that the development is accomplishing the prerequisites for making mixed-income
housing into a community. Low rents and promises of safety appeal to all households
and are attracting middle-income households.
One-half of units are non-project for residents of middle-income
level. Middle-income households insist that the management rules be strictly
enforced leading to improved levels of satisfaction with the environment of
the development.
Although some social interaction is being experienced, residents have not
seen significant employment outcomes over the four-year period of the study.
Experiment is not without critics. Vale (1998) argues that Lake Park Place
does not indicate that mixed-income housing is working. The project has become
a well-managed development with improved amenities and strict management policies.
None of these outcomes required conversion to mixed-income housing. Public
housing can enjoy these outcomes without the conversion to mixed-income occupancy.
Case: Old City Hall
Kansas City, Kansas
Type: Conversion of municipal building to lofts.
Old City Hall, built 1911, on the National Register of Historic Places.
Subsidies: Low-Income Housing Tax Credit.
Historic Rehabilitation Tax Credit.
Land and building donation by the city.Background: 40 lofts (24 tax credit
and 16 market-rate units)
Units from 540 to 1,670 square feet with rents $291 to $935 per month
Located in downtown Kansas City, Kansas
Downtown is suffering from considerable deterioration
Revitalization assisted by construction of Federal Court housing, EPA offices,
plus new municipal office building and small convention center/hotel.
Location is on dividing line between commercial area and aging Strawberry
Hill neighborhood, which is enjoying some gentrification.
Overall market is soft, but two recent multi-family developments nearby
have waiting lists.
Nearby loft market in adjacent Kansas City, Missouri is vibrant with rapid
sales of condominiums and high occupancy rates on leased space. This market
includes many converted warehouses and office buildings. Rents are rising
at 9.5 percent per year; most are 100 percent occupied. The subject property
will compete directly with other recently renovated loft developments in the
Kansas City, Missouri area. The average rent for loft apartments are $870
for a one-bedroom unit and $1,040 for a two-bedroom unit. The lower rents
of the Old City Hall Building will make it competitive with the higher priced
lofts in adjacent areas.
The household income required to rent a city hall unit ranges from $16,600
to $41,400; ample downtown employees should be attracted.
Case Mixed-Income Inclusionary Zoning
Montgomery County, MarylandType: Inclusionary zoning at the county level.
Montgomery County, Maryland, middle-class suburb of Washington, D.C.
Subsidy: None, regulatory.
Illustration: Timberlawn Crescent, mixed-income development.
Total development costs: $7.6 million ($71,000/unit);
"Although numerous meetings were held to solicit neighborhood input
during the planning process and suggestions were included, residents of the
surrounding community vigorously opposed the development before the planning
commission. They did not believe that we were telling them the truth about
our design." But when they saw the actual buildings the neighbors' opposition
vanished.
Background: One of Montgomery Countys key tools is its Moderately-Priced
Dwelling Unit (MPDU) ordinance.
Enacted in 1973, the MPDU law requires private developers to build mixed
income housing everywhere.
The law covers any new subdivision, townhouse complex, or apartment development
with at least 50 housing units.
Under the county law up to 85 percent of the new housing can be "market
rate" (at whatever income level the builder targets), but at least 15
percent must be "affordable" housing, or MPDUs.
To qualify for an MPDU, a familys income cannot exceed 65 percent
of the countys average household income.
To help integrate poor households into middle-class society, the county
law further specifies that one-third of the MPDUs, or 5 percent of all housing
created, must be available for rent or out-right purchase by the Housing Opportunities
Commission, the county-wide housing authority.
Montgomery County does not build public housing projects. It purchases standard
housing units scattered across the county as rental housing for its poorest
households.
Complying with the Countys ground rules, private homebuilders and
apartment developers have produced over 10,000 MPDUs two-thirds for
sale, one third for rent.
Many buyers are local school teachers, county deputy sheriffs, office workers,
super market clerks, fast food cooks, the civil servants, retail trade and
service industry workers who serve local communities.
To house welfare recipients and other poor residents, the Housing Opportunities
Commission has purchased over 1,500 of the new MPDUs. (Church groups and private,
non-profits have bought others.)
The 85 percent market, 10 percent low, and 5 percent very-low income mix
produces few social problems, according to HOC officials and resale prices
have risen in mixed-income subdivisions faster than for non-mixed income housing
developments. Many social successes, such as low school drop out rates, have
been documented.
Case: Mixed-Income Inclusionary Zoning
Sacramento, California
Type: Inclusionary zoning at the municipal level.
Illustration: Southside Park Co-Housing, Sacramento, California
Subsidies: None, regulatory approach.
Background: In October of 2000, the Sacramento City Council adopted City
Code 17.190 establishing a Mixed-Income Housing Ordinance for New Growth Areas
within the City limits. This ordinance requires that any new residential development
of ten units or more include an affordable component.
Ten percent (10%) of residential units in the entire development must be
affordable to households with incomes at or below 50 percent of the area median
($26,450 for a four-person household), which is the definition of a "very
low-income" household.
Five percent (5%) of residential units in the entire development must be
affordable to households with incomes at or below 80 percent of the area median
($42,300 for a four-person household), which is the definition of a "low-income"
household.
Housing Type: Units can be single family, alternative ownership housing,
duplex, multifamily, or a combination. Developer should take full advantage
of multiple housing type and target average densities in the applicable Community
Plan.
Developer can choose to build affordable units, sell or donate land to affordable
housing developer, partner with others, or dedicate land to SHRA.
Planning Director can approve developer's request to dedicate land to SHRA
if more cost-efficient solution.
Units must be dispersed to maximum extent feasible, and built contemporaneously
with other residential components.
Inclusionary units must remain affordable for at least 30 years.
Exemptions:
Residential projects with nine or fewer residential dwellings in
one location (a defined term);
Rehabilitation of existing residential dwellings;
Market rate units produced as a density bonus;
Residential projects which had approved Development Agreements before
June 20, 2000.
Conclusion
Many definitions of mixed-income housing exists; none can claim superiority
over the others. The definitions set different levels to demarcate low-income
from upper-income, and many go further to distinguish between working households
of non-working households. Planners need to adopt the approach that is most
suitable the economic, social and political environment of their jurisdictions.
The benefits of mixed-income housing are found in many forms, but the source
of the benefits is in the social interaction between people of different economic
circumstances. The interaction can reduce the culture of poverty that can pervade
low-income housing projects. The interaction can provide access to networks
of contacts crucial to becoming gainfully employed. The interaction can provide
the role models that children need both in the classroom to succeed academically
and outside the classroom in the form of working adult role models. Given these
benefits, mixed-income housing can mitigate the political opposition that often
arises when low-income housing is proposed in a neighborhood with little or
no poverty.
Experience suggests that mixed-income housing works best in a tight housing
market, but this is not a perquisite. Mixed-income developments are working
in many normal and soft markets, but these require additional attention. Upper-income
households have choices, thus attracting them to mixed-income housing requires
some combination of rent breaks, high quality design and management of the development,
and usually, a resident population dominated by other upper-income households.
This usually means a full range of income levels among the residents and efficient
management that will strictly enforce rules of behavior across the development.
The MHC gives advice in assessing success: have patience. Perhaps the
most important measure of the success of a mixed income community is whether
children who grow up there are working steadily, ten years later. It may therefore
be the case that we will need to pursue mixed income approaches for some time
before the actual level of success becomes apparent.
Bibliography
Briggs, Xavier de Souza, et al. 1999. "In the Wake of Desegregation: Early
Impacts of Scattered-Site Public Housing on Neighborhoods in Yonkers, New York,"
Journal of the American Planning Association 65(1):27-49.
Brophy, Paul C. and Rhonda N. Smith. 1997. Mixed-Income Housing: Factors
for Success. Cityscape: A Journal of Policy Development and Research 3(2):3-31.
Corcoran, Joseph E. 2002. Making Mixed-Income Housing Work.
ULIthe Urban Land Institute.
Khadduri, Jill and Marge Martin. 1997. Mixed-Income Housing in the HUD
Multifamily Stock. Cityscape: A Journal of Policy Development and Research
3(2):33-69.
Leger, Mireille L. and Stephen D. Kennedy. 1990. Recipient Housing in the Housing
Voucher and Certificate Programs. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Housing
and Urban Development, Office of Policy Development Research.
Lee, Chang-Moo, Dennis P. Culhane and Susan M. Wachter. 1999. The Differential
Impacts of Federally Assisted Housing Programs on Nearby Property Values: A
Philadelphia Case Study. Housing Policy Debate 10(1):75-93.
McClure, Kirk. 2000. The Low-Income Housing Tax Credit Program as an Aid
to Housing Finance: How Well Has It Worked? Housing Policy Debate 11(1):91-114.
__________. 2001 The Twin Mandates Given to the GSEs: Which Works Best,
Helping Low-Income Homebuyers or Helping Underserved Areas? Cityscape:
A Journal of Policy Development and Research 5(3):107-143.
Millennial Housing Commission, Preservation and Production Task Forces. 2001.
Policy Option Paper: Mixed-Income Housing. Washington, D.C.: Millennial
Housing Commission.4
Newman, Sandra J. and Ann B. Schnare. 1997.
And a Suitable
Living Environment: The Failure of Housing Programs to Deliver on Neighborhood
Quality. Housing Policy Debate 8(4):703-42.
Rosenbaum, James E. et al. 1998. Lake Parc Place: A Study of Mixed-Income
Housing, Housing Policy Debate 9(4): 703-740.
Sacramento, California. 2000. City Code 17.190 establishing a Mixed Income
Housing Ordinance for New Growth Areas within the City limits.
Schwartz, Alex and Kian Tajbakhsh. 1997. Mixed-Income Housing: Unanswered
Questions. Cityscape: A Journal of Policy Development and Research 3(2):71-92.
University of Cincinnati. 1999. Mixed-Income Housing - Idealistic or
Realistic?
Real Estate Property Newsletter (Nov./Dec. 1999 ).
Wilkins, Charles S., Jr. 2001. Preservation and Production Task Forces
Concept Paper: Mixed-Income Rental Housing. Washington, D.C.: Millennial
Housing Commission.
Vale, Lawrence J. 1998. Comment on James E. Rosenbaum, Linda K. Stroh,
and Cathy A. Flynn's Lake Parc Place: A Study of Mixed-Income Housing.
Housing Policy Debate 9(4): 749-756.
Author and Copyright Information
Kirk McClure is an Associate Professor with the Graduate Program in
Urban Planning at the University of Kansas. His
teaching and research interests are in the area of affordable housing finance
and development. McClure has also worked as a professional planner
at both the state and local levels, working on many low-income and mixed-income
housing developments.
Kirk McClure, Associate Professor
Graduate Program in Urban Planning
University of Kansas
1465 Jayhawk Boulevard, 317 Marvin Hall
Lawrence, Kansas 66045-7614
Voice: (785) 864-3888
Fax: (785) 864-5301
E-mail: mcclure@KU.edu |